Constant Returns
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In
economics Economics () is the social science that studies the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. Economics focuses on the behaviour and interactions of economic agents and how economies work. Microeconomics analyzes ...
, returns to scale describe what happens to long-run returns as the scale of production increases, when all input levels including physical capital usage are variable (able to be set by the
firm A company, abbreviated as co., is a legal entity representing an association of people, whether natural, legal or a mixture of both, with a specific objective. Company members share a common purpose and unite to achieve specific, declared go ...
). The concept of returns to scale arises in the context of a firm's
production function In economics, a production function gives the technological relation between quantities of physical inputs and quantities of output of goods. The production function is one of the key concepts of mainstream neoclassical theories, used to define ...
. It explains the long-run linkage of the rate of increase in output (production) relative to associated increases in the inputs (
factors of production In economics, factors of production, resources, or inputs are what is used in the production process to produce output—that is, goods and services. The utilized amounts of the various inputs determine the quantity of output according to the rel ...
). In the long run, all factors of production are variable and subject to change in response to a given increase in production scale. While
economies of scale In microeconomics, economies of scale are the cost advantages that enterprises obtain due to their scale of operation, and are typically measured by the amount of output produced per unit of time. A decrease in cost per unit of output enables ...
show the effect of an increased output level on unit costs, returns to scale focus only on the relation between input and output quantities. There are three possible types of returns to scale: increasing returns to scale, constant returns to scale, and diminishing (or decreasing) returns to scale. If output increases by the same proportional change as all inputs change then there are constant returns to scale (CRS). If output increases by less than the proportional change in all inputs, there are decreasing returns to scale (DRS). If output increases by more than the proportional change in all inputs, there are increasing returns to scale (IRS). A firm's production function could exhibit different types of returns to scale in different ranges of output. Typically, there could be increasing returns at relatively low output levels, decreasing returns at relatively high output levels, and constant returns at some range of output levels between those extremes. In mainstream microeconomics, the returns to scale faced by a firm are purely technologically imposed and are not influenced by economic decisions or by market conditions (i.e., conclusions about returns to scale are derived from the specific mathematical structure of the production function ''in isolation'').


Example

When the usages of all inputs increase by a factor of 2, new values for output will be: * Twice the previous output if there are constant returns to scale (CRS) * Less than twice the previous output if there are decreasing returns to scale (DRS) * More than twice the previous output if there are increasing returns to scale (IRS) Assuming that the factor costs are constant (that is, that the firm is a perfect competitor in all input markets) and the production function is homothetic, a firm experiencing constant returns will have constant long-run average costs, a firm experiencing decreasing returns will have increasing long-run average costs, and a firm experiencing increasing returns will have decreasing long-run average costs. However, this relationship breaks down if the firm does not face perfectly competitive factor markets (i.e., in this context, the price one pays for a good does depend on the amount purchased). For example, if there are increasing returns to scale in some range of output levels, but the firm is so big in one or more input markets that increasing its purchases of an input drives up the input's per-unit cost, then the firm could have diseconomies of scale in that range of output levels. Conversely, if the firm is able to get bulk discounts of an input, then it could have economies of scale in some range of output levels even if it has decreasing returns in production in that output range.


Formal definitions

Formally, a production function \ F(K,L) is defined to have: *Constant returns to scale if (for any constant ''a'' greater than 0) \ F(aK,aL)=aF(K,L) (Function F is homogeneous of degree 1) *Decreasing returns to scale if (for any constant ''a'' greater than 1) \ F(aK,aL) *Increasing returns to scale if (for any constant ''a'' greater than 1) \ F(aK,aL)>aF(K,L) where ''K'' and ''L'' are factors of production—capital and labor, respectively. In a more general set-up, for a multi-input-multi-output production processes, one may assume technology can be represented via some technology set, call it \ T , which must satisfy some regularity conditions of production theory.
Zelenyuk V. (2014) “Scale efficiency and homotheticity: equivalence of primal and dual measures” Journal of Productivity Analysis 42:1, pp 15-24.
/ref> In this case, the property of constant returns to scale is equivalent to saying that technology set \ T is a cone, i.e., satisfies the property \ aT=T, \forall a>0 . In turn, if there is a production function that will describe the technology set \ T it will have to be homogeneous of degree 1.


Formal example

The Cobb–Douglas functional form has constant returns to scale when the sum of the exponents is 1. In that case the function is: :\ F(K,L)=AK^L^ where A > 0 and 0 < b < 1. Thus :\ F(aK,aL)=A(aK)^(aL)^=Aa^a^K^L^=aAK^L^=aF(K,L). Here as input usages all scale by the multiplicative factor ''a'', output also scales by ''a'' and so there are constant returns to scale. But if the Cobb–Douglas production function has its general form :\ F(K,L)=AK^L^ with 0 and 0 then there are increasing returns if ''b'' + ''c'' > 1 but decreasing returns if ''b'' + ''c'' < 1, since :\ F(aK,aL)=A(aK)^(aL)^=Aa^a^K^L^=a^AK^L^=a^F(K,L), which for ''a'' > 1 is greater than or less than aF(K,L) as ''b''+''c'' is greater or less than one.


See also

* Diseconomies of scale and
Economies of scale In microeconomics, economies of scale are the cost advantages that enterprises obtain due to their scale of operation, and are typically measured by the amount of output produced per unit of time. A decrease in cost per unit of output enables ...
*
Economies of agglomeration One of the major subfields of urban economics, economies of agglomeration (or agglomeration effects) describes, in broad terms, how urban agglomeration occurs in locations where cost savings can naturally arise. Most often discussed in terms of ...
*
Economies of scope Economies of scope are "efficiencies formed by variety, not volume" (the latter concept is "economies of scale"). In economics, "economies" is synonymous with cost savings and "scope" is synonymous with broadening production/services through div ...
* Experience curve effects *
Ideal firm size {{unreferenced, date=August 2013 The socially optimal firm size is the size for a company in a given industry at a given time which results in the lowest production costs per unit of output. Discussion If only diseconomies of scale existed, ...
* Homogeneous function *
Mohring effect The Mohring effect is the observation that, if the frequency of a transit service (e.g., buses per hour) increases with demand, then a rise in demand shortens the waiting times of passengers at stops and stations. Because waiting time forms part of ...
* Moore's law


References


Further reading

* Susanto Basu (2008). "Returns to scale measurement," ''
The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'' (2018), 3rd ed., is a twenty-volume reference work on economics published by Palgrave Macmillan. It contains around 3,000 entries, including many classic essays from the original Inglis Palgrave Diction ...
'', 2nd Edition
Abstract.
*
James M. Buchanan James McGill Buchanan Jr. (; October 3, 1919 – January 9, 2013) was an American economist known for his work on public choice theory originally outlined in his most famous work co-authored with Gordon Tullock in 1962, ''The Calculus of Consen ...
and Yong J. Yoon, ed. (1994) ''The Return to Increasing Returns''. U.Mich. Press. Chapter-previe
links.
* John Eatwell (1987). "Returns to scale," '' The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 4, pp. 165–66. * Färe, R., S. Grosskopf and C.A.K. Lovell (1986),
Scale economies and duality
Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 46:2, pp. 175–182. * Hanoch, G. (1975)
The elasticity of scale and the shape of average costs
” American Economic Review 65, pp. 492–497. * Panzar, J.C. and R.D. Willig (1977)
Economies of scale in multi-output production
Quarterly Journal of Economics 91, 481-493. *
Joaquim Silvestre Joaquim is the Portuguese language, Portuguese and Catalan language, Catalan version of Joachim and may refer to: * Alberto Joaquim Chipande, politician * Eduardo Joaquim Mulémbwè, politician * Joaquim Agostinho (1943–1984), Portuguese profe ...
(1987). "Economies and diseconomies of scale," ''The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 2, pp. 80–84. * Spirros Vassilakis (1987). "Increasing returns to scale," ''The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 2, pp. 761–64. *
Zelenyuk V. (2014) “Scale efficiency and homotheticity: equivalence of primal and dual measures” Journal of Productivity Analysis 42:1, pp 15-24.


External links




Video Lecture on Returns to Scale in Macroeconomics
{{Authority control Production economics